- Research
- Open access
- Published:
Rewealthization in twenty-first century Western countries: the defining trend of the socioeconomic squeeze of the middle class
The Journal of Chinese Sociology volume 8, Article number: 4 (2021)
Abstract
The wealth-to-income ratio (WIR) in many Western countries, particularly in Europe and North America, increased by a factor of two in the last three decades. This represents a defining empirical trend: a rewealthization (from the French repatrimonialisation)—or the comeback of (inherited) wealth primacy since the mid-1990s. For the sociology of social stratification, “occupational classes” based on jobs worked must now be understood within a context of wealth-based domination. This paper first illustrates important empirical features of an era of rising WIR. We then outline the theory of rewealthization as a major factor of class transformations in relation to regimes stabilized in the post-WWII industrial area. Compared to the period where wealth became secondary to education and earnings for middle-class lifestyles, rewealthization steepens society's vertical structure; the "olive-shaped" Western society is replaced by a new one where wealth "abundance" at the top masks social reproduction and frustrations below.
Introduction
The dynamics of wealth in the Western world is a central element of the inequality which has ballooned over the last 30 years (Piketty 2014; Wolff 2016; Saez and Zucman 2016; Chauvel et al. 2019). Piketty (2014) has demonstrated this trend on a global level, concluding that “capital is back.” Despite recent research on wealth inequality, the parallel trends pertaining to income and wealth are not yet well understood (Jenkins 2009; Kuypers and Marx 2016). While income is more easily measured than wealth, the latter shows unambiguous transformations (Piketty 2014; Saez and Zucman 2016; Chauvel et al. 2019). Analyzing joint relations between income and wealth may help explain the process of a squeezed middle class, and the contradictory nature of progressive tendencies (e.g., educational expansion, gender parities) yoked together with destabilizing tendencies (e.g., legitimation of elitism, middle-class malaise) to differing degrees across welfare regimes (Gornick and Jäntti 2013; Cowell and Van Kerm 2015; Mijs 2019; Semyonov and Lewin-Epstein 2013; Semyonov et al. 2013; Skopek 2015; Chauvel and Hartung 2016; Cowell et al. 2017; Chauvel 2019).
Our main objective in this paper is to assess the relevance of a comeback of wealth as a crucial resource for defining one’s social position in the conceptualization of social class. Relying on a theory of pluralistic middle-class fractions initially developed by Gustav Schmoller and Pierre Bourdieu (Chauvel 2020), we focus here on a successive disruptive factor in stratification dynamics: the comeback of wealth and its major consequences on Western social class systems (Chauvel 2006). The “rewealthization”—or repatrimonialization translated literally from French—presupposes a previous period of “dewealthization” (dépatrimonialisation in French). Dépatrimonialisation constituted a trend of wealth moderation promoted by the development of strong welfare states. In the post-World War II (WWII) industrial era, the conception of class analysis for Western countries was largely based on the male head of households’ employment, particularly their occupational class, since occupation represented the main structured source of hierarchy among men (and their families): where educational expansion led the competition for jobs and differentials between occupations acted as a primary source of income inequality in society. This in turn grew to encompass women’s entry into a post-industrial workforce and class divisions according to their own labor income. In the wealth-based society promoted by welfare state retrenchments, a newly fashioned hierarchy emerges in the mid-1990s. Over and above a hierarchy of occupations, it is now a hierarchy of ownership which once again becomes a major source of socioeconomic divide.
Contemporary sociologists specialized in social structure and class divisions tend to focus less on income and wealth distributions than on the employment relationship and occupations (typically, Erikson and Goldthorpe 1992, Goldthorpe 2013). In contrast, economic resources in flux (income) and stock (wealth) are the dominant focus in economic studies of the same fields (typically, Piketty 2014). Although many scholars (Bourdieu 1979; Wright 1997; Savage et al. 1992; Savage and Butler 1995; Savage 2015; Liu 2020) conceptualized mixed occupational and resource approaches, social class today is—for both men and women—more a question of what one does than of what one owns. In this context, the role of wealth is more systemic than the role of labor income; as the result of accumulated incomes over a lifetime and as a source of investments in the future, wealth can be transmitted from one generation to the next. Scholars have become increasingly aware over the years (Guo et al. 2018) that class structure is thereby a complex, systemic aggregation of a series of resources garnered from education, occupation, income, wealth, among others. An important aspect of the comeback of wealth in class analysis is to provide a characterization of the “middle class squeeze” problem on alternate and broader grounds than purely employment-based approaches (Wright and Dwyer 2003; Murphy and Oesch 2018; Peugny 2019).
The purpose of this paper is to situate the specific role of wealth in class systems across Western societies and to explore whether rewealthization constitutes a threat for the future stability of the class structure. We first establish the empirical reality of this trend. In a second part of the paper, we argue that this trend is a defining issue of our times with significant consequences for the middle classes. In a third section, we flash back to a former period in the twenty-first century, a period in which the new middle class emerged and rose to dominance as a social group in affluent, wage-based societies. In a fourth section, we contrast this with the more recent dynamics of wealth expansion and lower welfare moderation, which risks destabilizing middle-class lifestyles. We conclude with what rising wealth-to-income ratio may mean for future scenarios and a social morphology of Europe and North America in particular. The current prognosis is bleak: extreme affluence of wealth-based societies could marginalize ever more segments of society, potentially jeopardizing social stability.
“Wealth is back” as a new social fact
Between 1990 and 2020, many Western countries underwent a major transformation in equilibrium between wealth and income. There is a general shift in reliance on flux resources like labor incomes, wages, and premiums arising from economic activity to a reliance on stock resources like wealth, assets, capital, property ownership and rights. Empirical evidence for the occurrence of this rewealthization is found in the striking jump of the formerly balanced aggregated wealth-to-income ratio (WIR) over the 40-year timespan. Wealth-to-income ratios in eight major Western economies are given in Fig. 1, showing the ratio between average per capita net wealth (the total value of cash, housing, bonds, equities, etc., owned by the national economy, minus debts) and the per capita income (the gross domestic product minus fixed capital used in production processes plus the net foreign income earned by residents). Figures are obtained from the World Inequality database (WID) (Alvaredo et al. 2017) through our STATA programming based in the WID command (Blanchet 2017) as developed in the Supplementary information.
The trend of rewealthization varies across countries, but upward trajectories are particularly stark in Europe, notably France, Spain, and Sweden, as well as in North America, notably Canada (Chauvel and Hartung 2016). What we see is a doubling of the WIR over time, though the financial crisis of 2008 hit some countries, such as Spain, Greece or Ireland (Whelan et al, 2017) particularly hard.
Eastern Asian countries, in particular China, experienced similar developments of wealth but in an entirely different context. Western economic growth was, on average, weak in the period 1990–2020 and led to a general stagnation of wage incomes, whereas the rapid economic expansion in China benefited different social classes.
The US dynamic presents an interesting comparison and could constitute an exceptional case due to its relatively stable WIR. However, this is not to say that a trend of rewealthization did not take place in America, but rather that it took on a very concentrated, top-heavy, form. From 1990 to 2015, the average accumulation of net assets (wealth) in the US did not increase faster than average (labor) incomes. One explanation lies in the accumulation of public deficits, which reduced the net American wealth, as wealth accumulation of the median population became more difficult. Additionally, the US exemplifies a country which experienced a complete gutting of countervailing welfare moderation over the last three decades, and propelled the power grabs of an elite; government protections across the class structure were scrapped as only the top 1% of American society grew their allowances for exorbitant profit from their labor (Huber et al. 2019), but more importantly their wealth.
Since rewealthization in the US could be a story of exclusively super wealth, we narrow our analysis to the top wealth-to-average income ratio (TWIR). The TWIR indicator expresses the average top 1% accumulation of (net) wealth in numbers of years of mean incomes (Fig. 2).
In France, the TWIR ratio rose from 59 to 130 years equivalent of labor income between 1990 and 2015: the average wealth of the top 1% of the wealthiest French residents represented circa 60 years of average income accumulation in the 1990s, and two times more before the Covid-19 era. This is mainly due to the increasing WIR showing the systematic advantage of French owners during that period. In addition, at the very top, the development of earnings among finance managers played an important role for the increase in inequality in France (Godechot 2016). Contrary to the US, CEOs and entertainment superstars did not contribute to the development of inequalities in France.
In the US, the TWIR jumped from 100 to 171 years. Conversely, this trend cannot be attributed to the WIR (which was stable in the US), but to the expansion of wealth inequality. For a country like France, where the evolution is documented from 1913 onwards, the recent trend of repatrimonialization means a partial regression to pre-World War I (WWI) levels. In 1913, the average top 1% wealth represented 389 years of average income in France. The TWIR decreased to its lowest level of 52 years in 1985. As can be seen in Fig. 3, by 2015, the TWIR had increased again to 127 years. The value of 52 means that the aggregated value of the top 1% population’s wealth is equivalent to 0.52 years of net national income and an increase of 72 years of the TWIR (that soared from 52 years to 127 in France) means this 1% wealthy population now owns 1.27 year of net national income. This is still far from the almost 4 years of GNP that the French top wealthy population of 1913 owned at that time, but it is a clear trend in that direction.
Relevance of rewealthization for the socioeconomic transformations of our times
Wealth transformations have a major influence on socioeconomic inequality between social classes, but also within apparently homogeneous social classes. Without better knowledge of wealth inequality dynamics, the risk is to accelerate Mathew effects of cumulative advantages and disadvantages due to lack of social investment over the life course (Bonoli et al. 2017). More specifically, the wealth transformation in relation to income dynamics may explain why even in countries with stable income inequality (like France), people can be concerned about economic inequalities: wealth plays a determining role. As such, in many European countries, the Gini indices of income and wealth distribution are stable and yet the increasing WIR results in growing economic inequality: wealth means an increasing number of years of income accumulation, and debts longer periods of reimbursement. The WIR measures this inequality, which deepens when the top-end wealth of large proprietors is compared to the median income of the middle class.
The WIR, initially developed by Stiglitz (1969), is relevant in three dimensions. First, WIR growth measures the change from a wage-based society (relatively egalitarian work compensations as main resource) to a wealth-based society where rewards to work decline (Piketty 2014) and merit is threatened by the prevalence of inherited wealth (Killewald et al. 2017; Ponomarenko 2017). The second dimension is comparative social fact: the doubling of the WIR in many Western countries over the past three decades is a defining issue of our times. The third aspect relates to the distributional structure of income and wealth.
A representation of those differences is exhibited by the “strobiloid” curve (Chauvel 2016), density curves derived from the Pareto (1896) distribution and obtained with kernel density estimation (Van Kerm 2005). The harmonization of scales and surfaces allows comparisons of shapes. The strobiloid opposes the smoothed density curve of the median income (i.e., level of living, defined as the post-tax and transfer net income by consumption unit) to the curve of median net wealth. In more egalitarian countries, the income distribution presents a somewhat “olive shaped” (Li and Zhu 2016) distribution with a rather homogeneous median class, and a small proportion of the population appear at the extremes of affluence or poverty. The strobiloids of wealth are completely different, since the median class of wealth is weak and squeezed between the extreme poor with next to no wealth and the super rich with wealth that sits far above the middle of the wealth distribution.
Figure 4 presents these strobiloids for six Western countries. What each of these country cases illustrates is that density near median wealth is extremely low. By contrast, income inequality varies; income inequality is at a minimum in Finland, with a large population density near to the median, and at a maximum in the US, where the shape is pyramidal. Some Southern European countries, Luxembourg, Poland, and Slovakia, show a slightly stronger density near the wealth median, meaning a model of wealth accumulation in the middle. Unlike income however, wealth does not define a strong middle class in the majority Western countries.
The Gini indices of wealth are relatively stable in Europe and slowly increasing in the US (Chauvel et al. 2018). However, the almost doubled WIR has a major impact on economic inequalities overall due to the shift away from relatively moderate inequalities based on work differentiation (with Gini indices close to .3 in Europe) to much larger inequalities generated through the accumulation of capital (with Gini indices above .6).
Moreover, in societal systems where income inequality is mostly based on work or wages, an individual’s occupation is a measurable, highly visible dimension in the assessment of socioeconomic class definition. By contrast, in the more recent wealth-based society, families’ wealth accumulation is often a less objectively recorded and more veiled source of power and socioeconomic position, demonstrated by the gendered consequences of marital breakdowns where family inheritance concerned (Bessière 2019).
Another consequence of the lack of symmetry between income and wealth (Fig. 4) is in terms of class structure and social dynamics. When inequalities in health, education, and pension are indexed on the lifelong accumulation of households’ savings, like in wealth-based societies before WWI, after neoliberal reforms (Mau 2015) or common in Latin America (Méndez and Gayo 2019), the inter-decile ratio may reach 300 or even more. Under these circumstances, we can witness a dual social structure where two scales of inequalities coexist: the one of income inequality that remains of limited intensity, and the extreme polarization of the wealth distribution where social gradients are potentially boundless. In the US, where the cost of health, education, or old-age savings for seniors’ livelihood are ultimately based on families’ wealth accumulation, the extreme contrasts between the haves and the have-nots are exacerbated. This shift from wage to wealth-based society comes with a massive “sling effect” of wealth inequalities (Chauvel 2016): with the properties of Pareto tails of a distribution, increasing inequalities have a squeezing effect on the middle class, one of extreme acceleration of growth in the top 1% of the distribution. These 1% are the segment that enjoyed disproportional gains in newer wealth-based societies.
This trend implicates an important source of distortions—or even tensions—in socioeconomic positions. In the Golden Age of wage-based middle-class societies, when earned incomes were the major source available for consumption or savings, middle classes had a relatively homogeneous self-definition in terms of socioeconomic wellbeing. The relative prestige of neighborhoods, house sizes, and cars were relatively well determined by the purchasing power of households’ earnings. In a wealth-based society, each social stratum, even in the middle class, shows an inner polarization between extremely wealthy members who can afford a standard of living of much richer social groups, and others who must consider the consequences of their limited wage realities (Leicht and Fitzgerald 2013; Temin 2017). For instance, it is common in prestigious universities to see academics of different wealth backgrounds, many live like standard petty-bourgeois, and others own luxury properties in one or several global cities.
An important question the trend of rewealthization raises concerns the consequences of a shift from a strong egalitarian welfare state promoting a dense median wage-earner middle class (typically the corporatist welfare state) to a new wealth-based society where important segments of private and social consumption are available through a market competition of accumulated resources. Where governments have provided little protection from market bidding, such wealth inequalities have been shown to encourage the middle class to take on debt to try and ensure their stability and engage in bidding wars for “positional goods” such as private education and prime housing—one which the wealthy win at greater cost to the rest (Ahlquist and Ansell 2017).
In terms of income, we can suppose a strong homogeneous “median class”, while in terms of wealth, an extreme polarization exists between no-wealth families and the top wealthiest and no homogeneous median class. When “wealth is back,” the disaggregation of the middle class is not necessarily coming from an increase of the income Gini index, but from the growing importance of accumulation measured by the WIR. When the WIR grows like the TWIR (that measures the relative advantage of the richest population to the middle of the income distribution), the same university tuition fee represents an entire lifetime of savings for some middle-class parents, or a casual check amounting to pocket money from wealthy grandparents.
The emergence of middle-class societies in post-WWII Western countries
In a previous paper on the history of Western middle class in Europe, Chauvel (2009) described the emergence of the idea of middle-class societies in the late nineteenth century with key thinkers of the coming “new middle class,” including Simmel, Schmoller, or Bernstein (see also Charle 2002). An important aspect is the risk of anomic destabilization the middle class can sustain in case of brutal economic recession: Lederer and Marschak (1926) and Geiger (1930) anticipated the “Panic in the middle class” (Geiger 1930) that eventually contributed to the rise of fascist empires. In the post-WWII era, in a context of relatively rapid and egalitarian reconstruction of Western economies, a new model of society emerged: the “middle class society” that resulted in a process of “middlization.”
A more systemic approach than the measurement of inequality can be achieved with a broader conceptualization of “middle class societies.” Drawing on various classical social science works (notably Galbraith), the typical middle-class societies of the industrial times that culminated in the Western world in the eve of the 1980s can be described by seven important parameters—or seven “pillars” of “middlization.”
-
1.
Well above the level of the working class, a new group of wage earners emerges with stable and predictable earnings around the median wage; career stability becomes a norm (or at least a typical model in the public sector and then imitated by large companies in the service sector such as banks, insurance companies, etc.). This model of average wage earners generates a pervasive model of wage-based middle class society.
-
2.
In Galbraith’s (1958) model of the affluent society, the standard of living increases over the life course leading to increasing levels of consumption as well as savings (in particular in home ownership). The wealth-to-income ratio is low and the median earnings are sufficient for enjoying comfort, which is a new feature compared to former societies, where wealth was the nodal resource. This model promotes equality through wage moderation at the top of the distribution (Fourastié 1979), in a context of sustained rapid economic growth where no social strata is deeply frustrated.
-
3.
Welfare state development complements the protection provided by the permanent wage earner contract (lower volatility) extending thus social citizenship. Major social risks (widowhood, retirement, health, unemployment, old-age poverty etc.) are better covered by developed social insurance regimes (Ferragina and Seeleib-Kaiser 2011; Schröder 2019). In this model, social protection is a form of depatrimonialisation: wealth ownership is no more a condition of predictability.
-
4.
Galbraith underlined the specific role of education, not only for obtaining selective skills that define the “new middle class” by comparison to the old one based on petty property, workshop, and boutique, but also for values and identity of middle-class parents who measure their own social success based on the educational performance of their children (i.e., entry ticket to upward social mobility). Thus, a middle-class society is characterized by a growing, publicly funded tertiary education sector (“educational boom”), able to offer younger generations greater human capital as the stepping-stone for upward social mobility and thus fostering the belief in a meritocratic society.
-
5.
In the 1970s, values of socioeconomic progress and an optimistic vision of a never-ending search of personal and collective improvement in human development as well as economic, technological, and scientific progress characterized middle-class societies. In the American history of the middle class, the late 1960s were the climax of the belief in progress (“Man on the Moon”).
-
6.
In the context of the post-war Golden Age (US/UK), Miracolo economico (Italy), Rekordåren (Sweden), Wirtschaftswunder (Germany), or Trente glorieuses (France) (Fourastié 1979), the middle class became an increasingly powerful political force. Traditional politics were based on the fight between the dominant bourgeois powers and the social critique of proletarian streams. Trade union forces were initially devoted to the defense of working class interests, not the median wage earner. In this political model, the middle class had in many countries a very limited political choice and often joined the bourgeoisie in right wing voting. Later, with its increasing size, the middle class gained political centrality in democratic elections (the so-called median voter). In the context of the post-1968 social movements, trade unions had been able to include large fractions of the public sector new middle class, in particular in Continental Europe. By the late 1980s, unions in the Scandinavian countries had widened their influence to include large segments of the growing middle strata (Marklund 1988).
-
7.
Middle-class values in a middle-class society fit with the Aristotelian ideal of moderation, stability, and rationality. Due to progressive change in the context of post-materialist societies, the older political balance between proletariat and bourgeoisie gave way to the promotion of the middle class as a centered moderated actor, as prophesized by Simmel or Bernstein.
These seven parameters, typical of the Golden Age period of equalitarian expansion in Western countries, can generate a core of centripetal forces typical of middle-class societies. They are not only defined by a large proportion of middle-class members, but rely also on the consciousness of bourgeoisie and working class that their own social destination (or their children) is in the middle class. The centripetal forces are typical of the 1970s’ spirit where even non-middle-class actors, in the skilled working class and elsewhere, share some of the new middle-class interests (Kocka 1981).
Diagnosis of middle-class societies: are there symptoms of a destabilizing social class?
The inversion of Galbraiths’ seven parameters is typical of centrifugal dynamics from the middle class. The destabilization of the former middle class trends gain in importance in periods of economic retrenchments and might produce a generation of young adults marked by a pessimistic Zeitgeist (spirit of the time, Mannheim 1928). The outline here is more programmatic than a definitive demonstration as that would require more systematic, comparative, long-range validation. The main claim here, however, is that elements of social destabilization that concerned the working class are climbing the socioeconomic ladder and reach at least the lower middle class. This section systematically re-assesses the seven arguments presented above to test the hypothesis of “a destabilizing middle class”: do we witness a general reversal of the seven trends in the post-Golden Age period and thus a decay of the middle class society?
-
1.
Loss of stability in careers and fluctuations in the labor market generate wage uncertainty and thus difficulties to make plans for the middle class. A new massive precariat (Standing 2011) emerges in middle-class societies, particularly among younger generations (Mayer 2009). This status uncertainty includes new risks of over-indebtedness and vulnerability (Russell et al. 2012; Ahlquist and Ansell 2017). One of the strongest transformations of the middle class is its relation to security, in terms of lifelong control of adverse events. The security of a permanent job, or sufficient and scheduled working hours, is a central goal for the majority of the population, one which has been achieved by masses of wage earners in the 1960s, early on in their lifetimes. In the American case, increasing vulnerability of large segments of the lower middle class (Newman 1988; Newman and Chen 2007) become an obvious threat for the children of the Golden Age middle class. The consequences in terms of health, anticipated by Therborn (2013), have been extensively documented recently, where “deaths of despair” are the conclusion of increasing collective insecurity (Case and Deaton 2020).
-
2.
The slowdown in economic growth negatively affects wage earners, even in “affluent societies.” The income stagnation is even clearer when we consider net wages, after payroll and income tax. Globalization (Milanovic 2016), market competition between continents, and automatization (Autor 2015) accelerate this trend. Moreover, we observe an increasing gap between economic growth (GDP per capita) and median net wages (after tax) which stagnates in many countries (Nolan et al. 2016). These trends differ by Welfare regime but accompanying a superficial upgrading of native men and women’s by occupational employment is a destabilization of their ability to rely on a lifetime of middle-class living standards (permitted by a capacity to avoid overindebtedness, buy property, have guaranteed hours, pensions, wages, permanent contracts) (Oesch 2015; Chauvel and Bar-Haim 2016).
-
3.
A model of wage earner protections facing welfare state retrenchments, and the erosion of public insurance or its replacement by private insurances, wreaks havoc on household incomes—even in Nordic countries (Farrants and Bambra 2018). Targeted and means-tested welfare regimes progressively exclude the middle class from social protection: the poorer being protected and the richer able to afford their own needs on the market, the median being too rich to be protected and too poor to be dominant in market competition. As a consequence, savings, business resources, and capital gains make an increasing difference in individuals’ protection, where wealth accumulation, not social contributions to collective insurance systems, forms the major source of personal protection against risks. This means a large trend reversal after a complete twentieth century of Welfare State construction and decommodification described by Esping-Andersen (1990), in a new trend of recommodification and return to market-based provision of “social protection” (Schrecker and Bambra 2015) and thus rewealthization. This destabilization opens up new vulnerabilities over the entirety of the life course (Spini et al. 2017).
-
4.
In several countries (e.g., Italy, Spain), even the highly educated face difficulties in entering the labor market, generating a mismatch between education and socioeconomic positions, also known as overeducation (e.g., nimileuristas in Spain). Beliefs in the intrinsic value of mass education erode and middle-class members become conscious of risks of sudden social downward mobility (Attewell and Newman 2010). This is neither specific to Southern Europe nor the lower middle class—in countries like Great Britain, a tertiary level degree holds no more protective power against episodes of being Not in employment, education or training (NEET) in young adulthood than finishing school does (Platt 2007; Holmes et al. 2019).
Characterized by 40 years of increased (bar cyclical) unemployment rates, France provides an interesting illustration of this process of decline in the predictability of wage earner status. On the one hand, we can claim education is more and more protective, relatively, against unemployment since the gap between the educated population and the less educated has grown over time. On the other hand, in this process of acceleration of inequalities, diplomas lose their absolute protective power. In this respect, education is becoming a more necessary and less sufficient resource (Bar-Haim et al. 2019). This contributes to the long-term development of uncertainty and malaise in the wage earner society, in particular in the young generation (Karonen and Niemelä 2019; Yeung and Yang 2020).
-
5.
In Europe, declining trust in the European Union construction and, in America, the increasing difficulties in the promotion of interpersonal trust and civil society participation (Skocpol 2000; Putnam 2007) provide an impression of declining belief in the future, progress, and science. In Geiger’s model, economic degradation, downward mobility of circumstances, and the lack of a reliable and stable regulating frame generate fear, frustration, and social disorganization. A strong core of shared values and sense of solidarity can limit centrifugal trends but when they are absent, societies face the risks of anomie and social unrest, trends typical of the French 2018 “yellow vest” movement of frustrated downward mobile individuals of the lower middle class (Chauvel 2019). We will not elaborate on this in detail here but the Covid-19 events provided Western population with new worries such as the feeling that even Western science is no longer able to solve emergent issues.
-
6.
Declining participation in the institutions of social democracy, in particular in trade unions, marks the loss of political centrality of the middle class (Chauvel and Schroeder 2017). This comes with a trend of elitization of politics and of politicians in a winner-take-all process of political inequalities (Hacker and Pierson 2010; Jensen and van Kersbergen 2017) excluding the poor and the middle classes as well.
-
7.
Problems that were previously limited to socially excluded groups or the working class now spill over to the lower middle class. Populist parties progressively succeed in gaining votes in the middle class, for instance the Front National in France or the FPÖ in Austria (e.g., Pastor and Veronesi, 2018). Western countries including France, Italy, Hungary, and the Netherlands face disquieting drifts from their democratic ideals (a recent example would be the mainstreaming of far-right political messages by way of a steady incorporation of rightwing agendas into prominent parties in the Netherlands Witteveen 2017). In France, the “Yellow Vest Movement” exemplifies anomic trends and populistic temptations in the lower-middle-class fractions experiencing downward mobility (Chauvel 2019).
Conclusions: lasting consequences
The trend of rewealthization in Western countries, shared with some Eastern-Asian countries, is particularly difficult in the West since it is not mitigated by the massive economic acceleration that in particular China has enjoyed in the last generation (Li 2013; Li 2014). This notion is important and needs to be understood (i) in its dimension of reconstitution of wealth as a potentially massively asymmetric resource between the haves and the have-nots, (ii) in its relations with the reconstitution of family dynasties of assets controllers, and (iii) due to the asymmetric political power relations benefiting those who possess wealth, there are new potentialities of privatization of public resources in the interests of the wealthiest classes.
The former dynamic of “dewealthization” that culminated in the decades after World War II was driven by declining housing costs, the reduction (or even the marginalization) of private wealth as a source of economic power, the correlative expansion of wage as resource, and the increasing role of the State in strategic economic sectors that were previously managed under a traditional mode of capitalist control. In France, important sectors, such as railways, strategic industries (mining, energy production, automotive industry, etc.), and even banks, were typically nationalized in a context where the owners (individuals and families) of these former private companies accepted to take over a prominent political influence and role in the current public affairs, in search for more citizenship honor and less economic affluence. In the French experience, the most visible transformation of the French central bank Banque de France that was the private property of old bourgeois and aristocratic families (“Les deux cents familles”, the two hundred families who owned the central bank), a system that collapsed in the reforms of 1936 and disappeared with its nationalization of 1945 in the public Central Bank of France. This aspect of private money gaining exorbitant recognition in the (im)balance of public power can evoke a modern counterpart of Max Weber’s concept of patrimonialism, when public institutions become hereditary family property.
The process of rewealthization is a backlash dating back to the 1990s (earlier or later depending on the country) when we observed the formation of a gap between pure wage earners, even with competitive credentials, diploma, and marketable skills, who are structurally unable to become homeowners, and wealth accumulators. This new structure of socioeconomic power reconfigures the middle classes: the new divide improves the relative position of seniors (juniors can become wealth accumulators, but have difficulties to be before age 50, in a demographic regime of high life expectancy) and especially reconstitutes the relative socioeconomic power of wealthy families over the others. Another aspect which we have not covered in this paper, but for which there are signs of an inverted order of older inequalities that could be morphing into new inequalities is a gender differentiation in WIR. In the welfare regime long touted for progressive gender egalitarian laws and labor market, Sweden, there are indications in top income dynamics that as increasing numbers of women now reach the top 1% of earners on the back of their labor incomes, they have dropped from 18 to 17% of the top group were wealth (capital) taken as their only resource. The role of wealth (capital, and realized gains) has switched from being more important for women than for men in the 1970s, to being the most important resource, and source of growth, for men not women by 2017 (Boschini et al. 2017). Many pieces of the wealth puzzle remain hidden, which future research might address by means of simulations based on known distributions and measured trends, to better quantify the expected divide within the middle class between those who own and those who do not.
The present diagnosis rests upon the systematization of observations in Western countries in the last three decades before the Covid-19 PANDEMIE, CONFIRMING THE MIDDLE CLASS CRISIS. In this period, China escalated the ladder to the opposite direction with the expansion of a stronger middle class (Li 2014), even if trends of rewealthization are debated (Xie and Jin 2015; Piketty et al. 2019; Li and Fan 2020). The reactions to the Covid-19 outbreak underlined once again the frailty of Western societies in terms of public health and problems of social consensus and resilience. This frailty encompasses responses to social challenges expressed by two scenarios of inequality. One scenario is of a recovery in the context of a more balanced growth based on policies of inequality reduction (Atkinson 2016). The opposite one is of an acceleration of previous Western social challenges: recession on several indicators of human development, and a radical divide between the haves and the have-nots to reconstitute the extreme inequality structures of the nineteenth century (Chauvel 2019; Case and Deaton 2020).
Even if European societies continue to define themselves as olive-shaped, debates emerge there on the accurate description of the new structure, which might be more rigid than the “圭(gui)-shaped” one (Liu 2020): for the Western middle-class, long-term economic slowdown reduces opportunities of structural social mobility. Abundance at the pinnacle of Western society could stand for scarcity for the rest, with stagnation and frustrations contributing to a potentially unstable equilibrium. This trend brings us far from a harmonious society of modest wealth.
Availability of data and materials
Data are public; codes are available upon request to authors.
Abbreviations
- TWIR:
-
Top wealth-to-average income ratio
- WIR:
-
Wealth-to-income ratio
- WID:
-
World Inequality Database
- NEET:
-
Not in employment, education or training
References
Ahlquist, J.S., and B.W. Ansell. 2017. Taking credit: redistribution and borrowing in an age of economic polarization. World Politics 69 (4): 640–675. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0043887117000089.
Alvaredo F., L. Chancel, T. Piketty, E. Saez & G. Zucman, 2017. Global Inequality Dynamics: New Findings from WID.world. American Economic Review, American Economic Association 107(5): 404–409.
Atkinson, A. 2016. How to spread the wealth: practical policies for reducing inequality. Foreign Affairs 95 (1): 29–33.
Attewell, P., and K.S. Newman, eds. 2010. Growing gaps educational inequality around the world. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Autor, D.H. 2015. Why are there still so many jobs? The history and future of workplace automation. The Journal Of Economic Perspectives 29 (3): 3–30.
Bar-Haim, E., L. Chauvel, and A. Hartung. 2019. More necessary and less sufficient: an age-period- cohort approach to overeducation in comparative perspective. Higher Education. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10734-018-0353-z.
Bessière, C. 2019. Reversed accounting: legal professionals, families and the gender wealth gap in France. Socio-Economic Review 0 (0): 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwz036.
Blanchet, T. (2017). WID: Stata module to download data from the World Wealth and Income Database (WID.world), Statistical Software Components S458357, Boston College Department of Economics, revised 27 Aug 2020.
Bonoli, G., B. Cantillon, and W. Van Lancker. 2017. Social investment and the Matthew effect: limits to a strategy. In The uses of social investment, ed. A. Hemerijck. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Boschini, A., K. Gunnarsson, and J. Roine. 2017. Women in top incomes – evidence from Sweden 1974-2013. Journal of Public Economics 181: 104115. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2019.104115.
Bourdieu, P. 1979. La Distinction, Critique Sociale Du Jugement, Paris, Editions De Minuit.
Case, A., and A. Deaton. 2020. Deaths of despair and the future of capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Charle, C. 2002. The middle classes in France: social and political functions of semantic pluralism from 1870-2000. In Social Contracts Under Stress. The Middle Classes Of America, Europe And Japan At The Turn Of The Century, New York, Russell Sage Foundation, ed. Olivier Zunz, L. Schoppa, and N. Hiwatari, 66–88.
Chauvel L., (2006), Are social classes really dead? A French paradox in class dynamics, in G. Therborn (dir.), Inequalities of the World, Ed. Verso, London.
Chauvel L. 2009, The transformation of the European class system and the middle classes adrift. In Formation of Middle Class in Comparative Perspective: Process, Influence and Socioeconomic Consequences. Beijing: Social Sciences Academic Press, ed, Chunling Li, 371-396.
Chauvel, L. 2016. The intensity and shape of inequality: the ABG method of distributional analysis. Review of Income and Wealth 62 (1): 52–68.
Chauvel, L. (2019). La spirale du déclassement. Les désillusions des classes moyennes, (The spiral of downward mobility. The delusions of the middle classes) (second edition). Le Seuil.
Chauvel, L. 2020. The Western Middle Classes under Stress: Welfare State Retrenchments, Globalization, and Declining Returns to Education. Universe of Russia 29 (4): 85–111. https://doi.org/10.17323/1811-038X-2020-29-4-85-111.
Chauvel, L., & Bar-Haim, E. (2016). Varieties of capitalism (VoC) and varieties of distributions (VoD): How welfare regimes affect the pre-and post-transfer shapes of inequalities? (No. 677). LIS Working Paper Series.
Chauvel L., E. Bar-Haim, A. Hartung, P. Van Kerm (2018), Increasing inequality in joint income and wealth distributions in the United States 1995-2013 in the Luxembourg Wealth Study Data, Working Paper for the Atkinson User LIS Conference, http://www.lisdatacenter.org/wp-content/uploads/files/uc2018-s6-2.pdf.
Chauvel L., Hartung A., (2016), Malaise in the Western Middle Classes, UNESCO (Ed.) World Social Science Report 2016. Challenging Inequalities: Pathways to a Just World, 164-169, https://unesdoc.unesco.org/ark:/48223/pf0000245860.
Chauvel, L., A. Hartung, P. Van Kerm, and E. Bar-Haim. 2019. Inequalities in income and wealth above the median: new measurements and results for Europe and the United States. Research on Economic Inequality 27: 89–104. https://doi.org/10.1108/S1049-258520190000027007.
Chauvel, L., and M. Schroeder. 2017. A prey-predator model of trade union density and inequality in 12 advanced capitalisms over long periods. Kyklos 70 (1): 3–26.
Cowell, F.A., B. Nolan, J. Olivera, and Ph. Van Kerm. 2017. Wealth, top incomes and inequality. In Wealth: Economics and Policy, ed. K. Hamilton and C. Hepburn. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cowell, F.A., and P. Van Kerm. 2015. Wealth inequality: a survey. Journal of Economic Surveys 29 (4): 671–710.
Erikson, R., and J.H. Goldthorpe. 1992. The constant flux. A study of class mobility in industrial societies. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. 1990. The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Farrants, K., and Bambra. 2018. Neoliberalism and the recommodification of health inequalities: a case study of the Swedish welfare state 1980 to 2011. Scand J Public Health. 46 (1): 18–26. https://doi.org/10.1177/1403494817709191 Epub 2017 Jul 14.
Ferragina, E., and M. Seeleib-Kaiser. 2011. Welfare regime debate: past, present, futures? Policy and Politics 39 (4): 583–611.
Fourastié, J. 1979. Les Trente Glorieuses Ou La Révolution Invisible, Fayard, Paris.
Galbraith, J.K. 1958. The Affluent Society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Geiger, T. 1930. Panik Im Mittelstand. Die Arbeit 7 (10): 637–654 http://library.fes.de/cgi-bin/digiarb.pl?id=01021&dok=1930&f=637&l=654&c=637.
Godechot, O. 2016. Financialization is marketization! A study of the respective impacts of various dimensions of financialization on the increase in global inequality. Sociological Science. https://doi.org/10.15195/v3.a22https://www.sociologicalscience.com/download/vol-3/june/SocSci_v3_495to519.pdf.
Goldthorpe, J.H. 2013. Understanding–and misunderstanding–social mobility in Britain: the entry of the economists, the confusion of politicians and the limits of educational policy. Journal of Social Policy 42 (3): 431–450.
Gornick, J., and M. Jäntti, eds. 2013. Income inequality: economic disparities and the middle class in affluent countries. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Guo, L., S. Li, R. Lu, L. Yin, A. Gorson-Deruel, and L. King. 2018. The research topic landscape in the literature of social class and inequality. PloS one 13 (7): e0199510.
Hacker, J.S., and P. Pierson. 2010. Winner-take-all politics: public policy, political organization, and the precipitous rise of top incomes in the United States. Politics & Society 38 (2): 152–204. https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329210365042.
Holmes, C., Murphy, E., & Mayhew, K. (2019). What accounts for changes in the chances of being NEET in the UK? SKOPE working paper, No. 128; July, Oxford.
Huber, E., J. Huo, and J.D. Stephens. 2019. Power, policy, and top income shares. Socio-Economic Review 17 (2): 231–253. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwx027.
Jenkins, S.P. 2009. Distributionally-sensitive inequality indices and the Gb2 income distribution. Review of Income and Wealth 55 (2): 392–398.
Jensen, C., and K. van Kersbergen. 2017. The politics of inequality. London: Palgrave.
Karonen, E., and M. Niemelä. 2019. Life course perspective on economic shocks and income inequality through age-period-cohort analysis: evidence from Finland. Review of Income and Wealth. https://doi.org/10.1111/roiw.12409.
Killewald, Alexandra, Fabian T. Pfeffer, and Jared Schachner. 2017. Wealth Inequality and Accumulation. Annual Review of Sociology 43: 379–404 https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-soc-060116-053331.
Kocka, J. 1981. Die Angestellten in Der Deutschen Geschichte : 1850 - 1980 ; Vom Privatbeamten Zum Angestellten Arbeitnehmer. Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht.
Kuypers, S., and I. Marx. 2018. Estimation of joint income-wealth poverty: a sensitivity analysis. Social Indicators Research 136 (1): 117–137.
Lederer E. & Marschak J. (1926), Der Neue Mittelstand, In Grundriss Der Sozialökonomik, Das Soziale System Des Kapitalismus, Grundriß Der Sozialökonomik, Ix. Abteilung, I. Teil. Tübingen, Mohr, 120-141.
Leicht, K.T., and S.T. Fitzgerald. 2013. Middle class meltdown in America: Causes, consequences, and remedies. Routledge.
Li, C. 2014. A profile of the middle classes in today’s China. Chap. 5. In Chinese Middle Classes: Taiwan, Hong Kong, Macao and China, ed. Hsin Huang and Michael Hsiao, 78–94. London and New York: Routledge.
Li, C., and Y. Fan. 2020. Housing wealth inequality in urban China: the transition from welfare allocation to market differentiation. Journal Chinese Sociology 7: 16. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40711-020-00129-4.
Li, P. 2013. People’s livelihood in contemporary China: changes, challenges and prospects. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing Company.
Li, P., and Di Zhu. 2016. Make efforts to develop an olive-shaped distribution pattern: an analysis based on data from the Chinese Social Survey for 2006-2013. Social Sciences in China 37 (1): 5–24. https://doi.org/10.1080/02529203.2015.1133432.
Liu, X. 2020. Class structure and income inequality in transitional China. Journal Chinese Sociology 7: 4. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40711-020-00116-9.
Mannheim K., (1990) (1928). Le problème des générations, Nathan, Paris.
Marklund, S. 1988. Welfare state policies in the tripolar class model of Scandinavia. Politics & Society 16 (4): 469–485. https://doi.org/10.1177/003232928801600404.
Mau, S. 2015. Inequality, marketization and the majority class: why did the European middle classes accept neo-liberalism? Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Mayer, K.U. 2009. New directions in life course research. Annual Review of Sociology 35: 413–433. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.34.040507.134619.
Méndez, M.L., and M. Gayo. 2019. Upper middle class social reproduction: wealth, schooling, and residential choice in Chile. New York: Palgrave Pivot Series.
Mijs, J.J.B. 2019. The paradox of inequality: income inequality and belief in meritocracy go hand in hand. Socio-Economic Review. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwy051.
Milanovic, B. 2016. Global inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization. Cambridge: Belknap Press.
Murphy, E.C., and D. Oesch. 2018. Is employment polarisation inevitable? Occupational change in Ireland and Switzerland, 1970–2010. Work, Employment and Society 32 (6): 1099–1117. https://doi.org/10.1177/0950017017738944.
Newman, K., and V.T. Chen. 2007. The missing class: portraits of the near poor in America. Boston: Beacon Press.
Newman, K.S. 1988. Falling from grace: downward mobility in age of affluence. Berkeley: University Of California Press.
Nolan, B, M Roser, and S Thewissen (2016), “GDP per capita versus median household income: what gives rise to divergence over time?”, Oxford INET Working Paper Series, No. 2016-03
Oesch, D. 2015. Welfare regimes and change in the employment structure: Britain, Denmark and Germany since 1990. Journal of European Social Policy 25 (1): 94–110.
Pareto, V. 1896. Cours d’économie politique professé à l’Université de Lausanne [Course of Political Economy]. Editeur Rouge: Lausanne.
Pastor, L., & Veronesi, P. 2018. Inequality aversion, populism, and the backlash against globalization (No. w24900). National Bureau of Economic Research.
Peugny, C. 2019. The decline in middle-skilled employment in 12 European countries: New evidence for job polarisation. Research & Politics. https://doi.org/10.1177/2053168018823131.
Piketty, T. 2014. Capital in the twenty first century. (A. Goldhammer, Trans.). Cambridge: Belknap Press: An Imprint of Harvard University Press.
Piketty, T., L. Yang, and G. Zucman. 2019. Capital accumulation, private property, and rising inequality in China, 1978–2015. American Economic Review 109 (7): 2469–2496. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20170973.
Platt, L. 2007. Making education count: the effects of ethnicity and qualifications on intergenerational social class mobility. The Sociological Review 55 (3): 485–508.
Ponomarenko, V. (2017). Wealth accumulation over the life course. The role of disadvantages across the employment history. Retrieved from https://orbilu.uni.lu/handle/10993/29219
Putnam, R.D. 2007. E Pluribus Unum: diversity and community in the twenty-first century. Scandinavian Political Studies. 30 (2): 137–174. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9477.2007.00176.x.
Russell, H., C.T. Whelan, and B. Maître. 2012. Economic vulnerability and the severity of debt problems: an analysis of the Irish EU-SILC 2008. European Sociological Review 29 (4): 695–706.
Saez, E., and G. Zucman. 2016. Wealth inequality in the United States since 1913: evidence from capitalized income tax data. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (2): 519–578.
Savage, M. 2015. Social class in the 21st century. London: Pelican.
Savage, M., J. Barlow, P. Dickens, and T. Fielding. 1992. Property bureaucracy and culture. Middle-class formation in contemporary Britain. London: Routledge.
Savage, M., and T. Butler. 1995. Assets and the middle classes in contemporary Britain. Social Change and the Middle Classes. London: UCL Press.
Schrecker, T., and C. Bambra. 2015. How politics makes us sick: neoliberal epidemics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Schröder, M. 2019. Varieties of capitalism and welfare regime theories: assumptions, accomplishments, and the need for different methods. KZfSS Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 71: 53–73. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11577-019-00609-7.
Semyonov, M., and N. Lewin-Epstein. 2013. Ways to richness: determination of household wealth in 16 countries. European Sociological Review 29 (6): 1134–1148.
Semyonov, M., N. Lewin-Epstein, and D. Maskileyson. 2013. Where wealth matters more for health: the wealth–health gradient in 16 countries. Social Science & Medicine 81: 10–17.
Skocpol, T. 2000. The missing middle: working families and the future of American social policy. New York: Norton.
Skopek, N. 2015. Wealth as a distinct dimension of social inequality. Vol. 14. Bamberg: University of Bamberg Press.
Spini, D., L. Bernardi, and M. Oris. 2017. Toward a life course framework for studying vulnerability. Research in Human Development 14 (1): 5–25.
Standing, G. 2011. The precariat: the new dangerous class. London: Bloomsbury Academic.
Stiglitz, J.E. 1969. Distribution of income and wealth among individuals. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 37 (3): 382–397.
Temin, P. 2017. The vanishing middle class: prejudice and power in a dual economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Therborn, G. 2013. The killing fields of inequality. London: Polity.
Van Kerm Ph. (2005) “AKDENSITY: Stata module to perform adaptive kernel density estimation,é Statistical Software Components S456101, Boston College Department of Economics, revised 21 Dec 2010.
Whelan, C.T., B. Nolan, and B. Maitre. 2017. Polarization or “Squeezed Middle” in the Great Recession?: A comparative European analysis of the distribution of economic stress. Social Indicators Research: An International and Interdisciplinary Journal for Quality-of-Life Measurement 133 (1): 163–184.
Witteveen, D. 2017. The Rise of Mainstream Nationalism and Xenophobia in Dutch Politics. Journal of Labor and Society 20 (3): 373–378. https://doi.org/10.1111/wusa.12290.
Wolff, E. N. (2016). Household wealth trends in the United States, 1962 to 2013: What Happened over the Great Recession? RSF. Retrieved from http://www.rsfjournal.org/doi/abs/10.7758/RSF.2016.2.6.02
Wright, E.O. 1997. Class counts: comparative studies in class analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wright, E.O., and R. Dwyer. 2003. The patterns of job expansions in the USA: a comparison of the 1960S and 1990S. Socioeconomic Review 1: 289–325.
Xie, Y., and Y. Jin. 2015. Household Wealth in China. Chinese Sociological Review 47 (3): 203–229. https://doi.org/10.1080/21620555.2015.1032158.
Yeung, W.-J.J., and Y. Yang. 2020. Labor market uncertainties for youth and young adults: an international perspective. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 688 (1): 7–19. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716220913487.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank scholars including Mike Savage, Goran Therborn, Li Chunling, Li Peilin, members of the Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences of China, the organizers of the Kunming conference in the context of 2019 CASS Forum "Road and Experience in the Founding of New China: Social Development during the Last 70 Years" (2019 中国社会科学论坛: 道路与经验:新中国社会发展 70 年学术研讨会), and the anonymous reviewers.
Funding
This work was supported by the Fonds National de la Recherche Luxembourg (FNR), FNR/P11/05 & FNR/P11/05bis.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Contributions
Louis Chauvel, who leads the Institute for research on socioeconomic inequality IRSEI of University of Luxembourg, wrote the paper; Eyal Bar Haim and Anne Hartung contributed to the research project on middle-class dynamics and to the final revision of the paper. Emily Murphy contributed to the final revision of the paper. The authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The authors declare that there are no competing interests.
Additional information
Publisher’s Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Supplementary Information
Additional file 1:
Stata do-file to generate WIR and TWIR figures.
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
About this article
Cite this article
Chauvel, L., Bar Haim, E., Hartung, A. et al. Rewealthization in twenty-first century Western countries: the defining trend of the socioeconomic squeeze of the middle class. J. Chin. Sociol. 8, 4 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40711-020-00135-6
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40711-020-00135-6